Book Reviews, Business & Money, Charles, Economics, Political Discussion & Analysis, Political Economy, Social Behavior
comments 10

Plutocrats: The Rise of the New Global Super-Rich and the Fall of Everyone Else (Chrystia Freeland)

From the cover, I expected this book to be a lightweight documentary version of Crazy Rich Asians, offering painfully amusing stories about the foibles of the super-rich, accompanied by cautions about the negative effects of such behavior upon the rest of America.  Plus, the picture of private jets in the driveway attracted me as a vision of my hoped-for future, since I am comfortably in the 0.1%, and much of my time is spent struggling to reach yet higher.  Instead, this book is a pretty dense, though rambling, web of analysis, with no funny stories at all.  Still, it’s modestly worthwhile in itself, and it has the additional benefit that it sheds light on today.

How is today different than 2012, when this book was published?  There are basically the same number of rich people, after all.  Trump is what’s different, of course.  I don’t think Trump is the explanation for, or relevant to, everything.  But the perception of the American plutocracy by ordinary Americans, of its attitudes and of how it got its money, is a large part of why Trump was elected.  This book, because it says nothing about Trump, says a great deal about Trump.

Print (PDF)

You Should Subscribe. It's Free!

You can subscribe to writings published in The Worthy House. In these days of massive censorship, this is wise, even if you normally consume The Worthy House on some other platform.

If you subscribe will get a notification of all new writings by email. You will get no spam, of course.  And we do not and will not solicit you; we neither need nor accept money.


Plutocrats is basically a compilation of statistics, intercut with anecdotes, mostly gleaned from the very many interviews the author, Chyristia Freeland (a semi-famous journalist, recently appointed Canada’s Minister of Foreign Affairs) conducted with the rich and powerful, everyone from Eric Schmidt to George Soros.  The latter, in fact, is mentioned every few pages, each time as a sage of unique wisdom and insight. (The Soros worship is so over the top, actually, that the reader wonders if Freeland has some relationship with him.)  Books organized around an author’s interviews with the powerful tend to smack of vanity in an author, who usually seems to think the reviewee’s aura rubs off, but other than with Soros, Freeland does a pretty good job of restraining fanboy-ism.

The author initially frames her book by citing the Kuznets curve—the idea that inequality necessarily diminishes as a civilization gets richer overall.  This was not an original idea with Simon Kuznets in the 1950s; the same concept was also advanced by Alexis de Tocqueville.  So far, though, the idea has been proven false—inequality is increasing as we get richer.  Why that is, and what will likely result, is the theme of the book.

Immediately, though, crops up a significant problem with Freeland’s book—a failure to sharply distinguish inequality of income from inequality of wealth.  She slides back and forth between the two, sometimes in the same sentence, treating them as functionally identical, which they are not.  Inequality of income is, in large degree, a statistical artifact, since the people at the top are often only there briefly, and something like 20% of the population is in the top 1% of income for at least one year in their lives.  Inequality of wealth, that is, of assets, is much more problematic if inequality is the focus, in that there is less turnover in who is wealthy, which means it is harder to reach the top (as I know myself, to my shame and sorrow—I am much farther from the top 0.01% in assets than in income).  The envy that is the inevitable fruit of inequality is reduced, at least in America, if people feel like they have a shot at reaching the top, which today, they increasingly do not.  But Freeland never even acknowledges this critical distinction.

This is not the only reason the book sometimes feels confused; another problem is that Freeland tries to achieve a global focus, by citing individuals and statistics from India, Russia, and China, but comparing inequality in those areas with inequality in America muddles matters rather than illuminating them, since the book again shifts rapidly among things that cannot be compared directly to each other.  On the other hand, the foreign oligarchs do add a frisson to the book—the Sword of Damocles position of many non-Western plutocrats is very obvious and chilling.  Freeland adduces the obvious cases of executed Chinese oligarchs and imprisoned Russian magnates, but several of the people she interviewed who were riding high in 2012 are not now.  For example, the Brazilian Eike Batista, who made tens of billions in oil and mining, and is noted in the book as among the ten richest men in the world, is now bankrupt and serving a thirty-year prison sentence.  I’d rather have less money and more security, myself.  I like to sleep easy at night.

Despite these problems, Freeland does a competent job laying out what modern inequality generally looks like, with nods to the Gilded Age as a precursor of today.  Not only is inequality increasing, and it has been for decades, most Americans are staying in the same position, at best, or falling backward (at least until very recently, with the advent of what looks like a genuine broad economic boom as a result of Trump’s economic policies).  It is only the upper crust that is registering, and hoarding, gains.  Americans, rich and poor, used to frown somewhat on inequality of outcome, and a great deal on inequality of opportunity.  But since the 1970s, this social consensus fragmented, both due to internal political changes, and to the impacts of technology and globalization.  The world as a whole got richer, and very many foreigners were pulled out of poverty by the free market (not by Western charity)—but large numbers of Americans did not share in the bounty, and the elites stopped caring.

If this book were written in 2018, Donald Trump would be the focus, with this feeling of unfairness and being left behind cited as a driver for his rise.  Instead, having gotten basic data out of the way, Freeland turns to explicating the culture of plutocrats.  She discusses that today’s rich largely are not rentiers; they made their own money, rather than inheriting it, and they work to keep it coming, rather than clipping bond coupons.  Many of the richest are innovators who provide value to consumers, or at least perceived value.  She discusses their consumption, but also their unhappiness, the risks they take, and the cost on their families (noting that, for all practical purposes, zero women count as this type of plutocrat—they feature only occasionally, as wives and as inheritors of wealth).  Not that the reader cries for them, but it does make the reader realize the plutocracy is not just a bunch of caricatures playing Mr. Moneybags.

The most important cultural characteristic, however, is that modern plutocrats are cosmopolitan citizens of the world, feeling essentially no loyalty to the countries of their birth.  I would add, in the case of most American plutocrats, that they affirmatively despise much of America and its culture, while sucking up to the “values” of foreigners.  This latter point Adam Smith foresaw, how liquid capital erodes loyalty to country, and this accurate perception of American plutocrats is a key driver of Trump’s success.  When American CEOs state openly that if “four people in China and India [are lifted] out of poverty and into the middle class, and meanwhile one American drops out of the middle class, that’s not such a bad trade,” it is no wonder that Trump has wide appeal.  It’s not just ideological, either—as Freeland notes, “Western businesses are less dependent on a prosperous domestic middle class because they can now sell to the rising middle class of the emerging markets.”  American CEOs can preen themselves on being progressive while making money, naturally taking advantage of the stability and protections, legal and otherwise, of America, while giving little or nothing to other Americans.

Finally, along the same lines of plutocrat culture, Freeland notes the “coarsening” effect of privilege and the feeling of plutocrats that “the world should be built around you and your needs.”  This is not news (I distinctly remember when I first became rich noting the creeping tendency to feel that the rules didn’t apply to me, something that has to be continuously fought against) and is why in past ages the obligations of the aristocracy to the masses were taken seriously and drummed into young aristocrats.  Unfortunately, along with the rest of taught virtue, that instruction is gone, and the result is the Rich Kids of Instagram, Dominique Strauss-Kahn, and myriad other appalling behavior.

Freeland then takes a lengthy tangent, talking about economic “superstars,” people at the top of various industries, from music to finance, who make vastly more than most in their line of work.  This effect compounds as society as a whole gets richer, since those with money chase hiring the best in every area, from lawyers to art, who by definition are in limited supply.  Technology enhances the effect—the top nineteenth-century opera singers could still only reach a limited number of people, but today’s superstars can often sell to millions.  All this is interesting enough, but feels a lot like padding out the book.

Next we get a second long tangent, talking about the impact on plutocracy of revolutions around the world, both real revolutions and economic revolutions such as technology in general and the Russian fire sale of assets.  (Freeland overrates the impact of computers; only someone quite ignorant could claim that computers are equivalent in impact to “electricity and the internal combustion engine.”)  All of these contributed to the composition of today’s plutocratic class, and Freeland seems to be trying to say that plutocrats risk a new revolution less beneficial to them, where heads end up on pikes.

Most interesting to me is how often, when Freeland quotes various plutocrats,  variations on the phrase “value creation” crop up.  That’s because many plutocrats get their wealth from non-productive activities, from businesses that most definitely do not create value.  We tend to focus on the high-profile actual creators of value:  whatever you may think of Jeff Bezos, he earned his money.  (It is far less clear, though, whether big companies that have enriched their owners, because people are willing to pay for what they offer, have actually created social value—if Facebook, Twitter, and Snapchat disappeared, and maybe Amazon too, the world would probably be better off.  Mark Zuckerberg is not Henry Ford or even Jay Gould.)  But many plutocrats, less high profile for good reason, got rich from crony capitalism of various types, ranging from overt bribery in many countries to regulatory capture in the United States, or from being transactions costs, as is true for much of the financial plutocracy and many of the lawyers.  That is not “creating value.”  Again, most of non-plutocratic America distinguishes how a plutocrat made his wealth; it is a variation on the known phenomenon that the working class resents those rich who are perceived to have earned their wealth much less than the parasitical rich, and far less than they resent the professional-management elite.

Freeland wanders along, ending up talking about “active inertia,” how every plutocrat eventually cannot keep up with change and remains stuck in his rut, except for truly wonderful and exceptional geniuses like, you guessed it, George Soros.  Finally, though, we get back on track, if the track is the problem with today’s plutocrats, with a whole chapter on rent-seeking.  Freeland channels my favorite academic, Luigi Zingales of the University of Chicago Booth School of Business (though she incorrectly characterizes him as a Republican).  Zingales makes the key distinction between being promarket and probusiness—most object less if people get rich by succeeding in the market, but the reality is that most plutocrats loathe the market, and want to use the government or other anti-competitive means to line their pockets.  Of course, the best recent example of such behavior is the massive bailouts of firms during and after the 2008 financial crisis, socializing losses while privatizing gains, all of which firms should have simply been forced into bankruptcy, their equity owners wiped out, and their executives disgraced.  Instead, Goldman Sachs bankers and their acolytes robbed America.  Zingales, less histrionic than me, is famous for noting that Treasury Secretary Henry Paulson, when he “argue[d] that the world as we knew it would end if Congress did not approve the $700 billion bailout . . . to an extent he was right:  His world—the world he lived and worked in—would have ended had there not been a bailout.  But Henry Paulson’s world is not the world most Americans live in—or even the world in which our economy as a whole exists.”  Damn skippy.

That’s just one example of rent-seeking in one industry.  And 2008 is merely the most naked example.  Unfortunately, though, Freeman does a bad job of providing specifics about rent-seeking, merely muttering darkly mostly about deregulation, which is not the main driver of crony capitalism.  Like Rana Foroohar in her book Makers and Takers, we never get the details, and as I complained when talking about Niall Ferguson’s recent The Square and the Tower, despite its immense power, the network of Goldman Sachs is never unraveled and exposed.  (I was talking to a Jewish friend of mine yesterday, who by chance mentioned that many Jews see criticism of George Soros and Goldman Sachs as anti-Semitic dog whistles.  For the record, I think Jews, and Israel, are awesome, and not just in the “some of my best friends are Jews” sense.  Even so, Soros is the Great Satan.)  In fact, deregulation is irrelevant to the point at hand, since regulation is mostly not designed to hamper crony capitalism, but rather to reduce fraud, so deregulation, to the extent it leads to a free market and is promarket, rather than probusiness, is the opposite of crony capitalism.  Freeman glosses over that this is exactly what Zingales says, even though she quotes him for this precise point.  The real problem, which Freeman only touches on in passing, is regulatory and legislative capture—the reader would benefit from more detail, such as for example how the stock offering market, which was hoped to be democratized by the Internet, is still a walled garden for underwriters who take no actual risk, just a massive slice off the top, of money that should go to stockholders.  Freeman isn’t wrong about rent-seeking, but her explanation is deficient.

The free market creates winners and losers, to be sure, and there is a strong argument that in the modern world, with the leverage that technology and globalization provides, the talented will always pull away from the mass.  Freeland hints at this, quoting Andrew Carnegie, “The experienced in affairs always rate the man whose services can be obtained as partner as not only the first consideration, but such as render the question of his capital scarcely worth considering:  for such men soon create capital; in the hands of those without the special talent required, capital soon takes wings.”  This is the truth; I can count on the fingers of one hand the number of people I know personally with the real talent to create capital in this way.  The vast majority of people, even those in the elite, simply are not capable at operating at the top level of actual wealth creation.  Such rare people (almost all men, again) will nearly always become rich, if they desire it.  But that does not absolve them of responsibility to the rest of society, and it is that disconnect that is the real problem with today’s plutocracy.  Freeland tell us, of “the institutions that permit social mobility,” that it takes “economic redistribution—i.e., taxes—to pay for those institutions.”  That’s false—almost all taxes are spent to line the pockets of the elite, or to provide create incentives for the poor, not the working masses, who struggle along.  Not to mention that most social mobility is not the result of government “institutions,” but of the right culture not hampered by the government.  The responsibility of plutocrats here is not to pay more taxes, but to pay attention, in business and politics, to the interests of those less successful.

Freeland ends by comparing us to Venice, which is said to have declined after its oligarchy closed its ranks to new entrants and clamped down on vigorous entrepreneurialism.  True enough, I think, but given that Venice never regained even a fraction of its power, security, or relevancy, that doesn’t help us much, nor does Freeland offer us even a hint of what we should do.

I have a few ideas, though!  We can start by having Congress break up all large finance entities and aggressively discourage future rent-seeking, capture and revolving door activity.  Among other methods we should forbid, under penalty of ten years’ imprisonment, any work of any kind in the financial industry by former government employees.  Also, anyone who has ever worked at Goldman Sachs, even as an intern or secretary, should be instantly fired from any position in the federal government and barred from ever working in government again.

It’s not just finance, though.  That’s the tip of the iceberg.  I think we should return to the Brandeisian view of antitrust law, viewing with deep suspicion all concentrations of corporate economic power.  In fact, Zingales and his podcast partner, Kate Waldock, were just discussing this on their excellent podcast “Capitalisn’t,” which I highly recommend you check out.  And there are some books coming out on this very topic, which I expect to review as well, since I think this is a critical matter.  For current purposes, we should just agree that we can erode the power of the plutocrats, and increase opportunity for all Americans, by judicious hammering of entities that have acquired excessive power and are using that power in a way that does not benefit all of America.


You Should Subscribe. It's Free!

You can subscribe to writings published in The Worthy House. In these days of massive censorship, this is wise, even if you normally consume The Worthy House on some other platform.

If you subscribe will get a notification of all new writings by email. You will get no spam, of course.  And we do not and will not solicit you; we neither need nor accept money.


PDF (Typeset)

10 Comments

  1. Another good review Charles. And yes, we shouldn’t confuse income and wealth inequality.

    But one of your statement rings really false – “something like 20% of the population is in the top 1% of income for at least one year in their lives” .

    The top 1% of income in 2017 was about $300,000. That statement would mean that 1 out of 5 households $300,000 or more a year (at least temporarily). That would really surprise me. Do you know where you got this from…?

    Also, that kind of moving up and down the income range (income mobility) has been declining in this country, and now sits lower than Europe(!). I can find the research reference if you’d like.

    Regards,
    Kevin

    • Charles says

      Thank you. I did it from memory, and it’s not quite right. Thomas Sowell has noted (I can get the cite) that “To say, as [Piketty] does . . . that ‘the upper decile is truly a world unto itself’ is to fly in the face of the fact that most American households—53 percent—are in the top decile at some point in their lives, usually in their older years. . . . Even the vaunted ‘top one percent,’ so often discussed in the media, is a level reached by 11 percent of Americans at some point in their lives.” So 11 percent, not 20 percent (and the figure may be a few years old, or even from before the financial crisis). Still, perhaps, the decile figure is perhaps more evocative.

      And yes–if you have more recent data, I’d be interested. My general feeling is the same as yours–whatever the numbers were, they are worse now than they were, and the Gini coefficient for income in the US is also quite “bad” and getting worse. This is a major problem in my estimation.

      • Charles says

        A good article! I made much the same point. But I am not sure it proves that inequality is not a major problem. First, as I noted, wealth is a much better measure. Second, as you note, it is usually older people who are richer. Up to a point that’s logical, but the reality is that old people have far too much, and yet feed far beyond their needs at the federal trough, though that’s a somewhat tangentially related problem to inequality as such. Third, through, wage stagnation is undoubtedly a big problem–and far worse than it appears. If you have the same wage you did thirty years ago, but the expectation is that you have an air-conditioned house twice the size, new cars, and a $1,000 phone, you are effectively worse off. You have to work harder, and your wife has to work too, creating a set of knock-on societal problems (which I will comprehensively address in an upcoming review).

        • I don’t disagree with any of those statements. And I don’t agree with the article as much as I did when I wrote it. I like to think that I am willing to change my mind. However, my point was intended to be specifically targeted at the question of “income inequality” as such, not the (admittedly related) topics of wealth inequality and other contributing factors to general quality of life disparities.

  2. Curt says

    Great review! And great commentary on the important areas which Freeland neglected.

    I too have seen the corruption of the FIRE industry up close. A sizable number of my former classmates were neck deep in the bailout. Corruption, yes it’s disgusting, yes it’s unfair, yes yes yes….but why does it happen? Of course human nature, but there are other more structural reasons. Please consider the absence of a peer competitor for a bit. A hegemonic power which has no peer competitor is a state where the elite no longer need to be allied with the governed. In fact, the governed become no different than the other minions in the global system – fodder for the elites. Actually even worse since the other minions have local elites, while compliant with the hegemon, do chaff. This absence of a need for an alliance between American elites and their governed creates an extremely hostile elite, and the feedback mechanisms exacerbate the problem.

    Many IR Realists were surprised that post-Cold War, a coalition of states did not coalesce to counter the US – since that is what Realist theory would predict. I have a hunch that the US was suckered into a security and economic posture by Germany, Russia, China, and Japan in what was a judo-esque move. Setting the US up for a massive internal rot until it lost its ability to compete. The coalition members would each pick a specific area of technical competition against the US. China, Japan, Russia, and Germany all are very advanced states, yet they don’t really compete with each other, in fact they are quite complementary to each other. In other words, they have created an informal Eurasian alliance.

    • I want to add a little to this conjecture. Imagine you are running the USSR in 1985. You look at the US and see a state that has an economy 5 times yours, global dominance of the world’s oceans, dominance of a majority of the world’s energy sources, and the single best piece of geography on the planet by an order of magnitude; furthermore the USA has all the other advanced states as allies. You on the other hand have a stagnant state, with an ideology which has served its usefulness long ago and is now a super liability, a collection of expensive dependent vassals allies, and a widening tech gap. Clearly to continue as foe #1 of America is a very bad strategy. You also know that the USA has imported a significant population of elites from eastern europe who do not share the same Christian culture as the host US population – in fact are extremely hostile to Christianity. Furthermore, you have had direct experience with this same ethnic group of elites in your own state for quite some time – eventually exporting as many as possible. Clearly the end game is to get the USA to tear itself apart, and the best way to do that is to encourage the US elites to be as hostile as possible to the folks they govern.

      What do, what do?????

      Answer: Deprive the US of a rival, removing the alliance between US elites and the folks they govern, thereby letting the naturally hostile tendencies of the imported US elites towards the host US population explode.
      http://articles.latimes.com/1988-12-12/local/me-14_1_uci-scientists

  3. Isaac Kellogg says

    It’s interesting that you picked “thirty years ago” as the date at which to peg for comparison today’s wages, as that leads to necessitating comparison of standard of living as the primary explicator of inequality. If, however, we reach back beyond the reforms of the Reagan era, all the way back to fifty years ago, when the United States was still on the gold standard, we find a different progenitor of difference between the generations’ P/E’s. In 1971, the federally mandated minimum wage was $1.25, and gold cost 35 federal dollars per Troy ounce. This means that the minimum wage was one-twenty-eighth the value of an ounce of gold. If that were true today, the minimum wage would be $65.04. Instead, it’s $7.25, the equivalent of $0.14 per hour in 1971 money. This disparity cannot be overstated. All the statistics about “stagnation” of wages since 1970 are flat-out lies. Wages have steadily gone down, year by year, even as whole industries have been moved overseas, with the excuse that they are no longer “profitable” to operate in America. No longer profitable, despite paying Americans less and less every year. Americans at the bottom are paid 99.8% less than they were fifty years ago, yet it still “isn’t profitable” to employ them. If we had undergone a renaissance of red tape, a flourishing of new regulations over that time, that would be understandable. But except for ADA and grievance studies dance therapy regulations (OSHA looks good on paper, but in practice it’s a paper tiger), there haven’t been any such. I suspect increased greed, not increased cost of doing business, is the primary culprit here.

    • Charles Haywood says

      Yes, that’s interesting. Of course, the gold price was also federally mandated at the time, so the comparison is not precise, and there are other variables. But I generally agree; the American worker has shared even less in increased prosperity (to the extent that such increased prosperity is real; see my thoughts on Graeber’s Bullshit Jobs) than it appears.

  4. Isaac Kellogg says

    My apologies, my finger slipped on the calculator. That should be “those at the bottom are paid 88.9% less than they were fifty years ago.”

    But still.

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *